A conversation on horizontal policies in public procurement

I was kindly invited to talk about centralisation and public procurement at the Law School of the University of Lisbon last week by Prof. Miguel A. Raimundo. At the event, Prof. Nuno Cunha Rodrigues provided an initial overview on the opportunities that centralisation can create for the pursuit of horizontal or secondary policies. Based on my general views (here), I opposed the use of centralisation to achieve secondary policy goals, for the standard economic reasons, as well as for the issue of the democratic deficit that would ensue from allowing centralised purchasing bodies to act as market regulators.

Prof. Cunha Rodrigues has followed up on our discussion via email and has provided me with some detailed remarks (plus a short rebuttal/further thoughts I am adding at the end)(*). With his consent, I am posting them below (in black), accompanied by my own reaction to his points (in blue). I hope this "virtual" conversation on horizontal policies in procurement will be of interest. By all means, please feel free to comment.



Dear Albert:

As I told you personally, I´m a great admirer of your work which I´ve been following through your several publications and your blog. I saw your last post and I just wanted to make some comments on it.

Far too kind.

As a matter a fact, I don´t have a close view on secondary or horizontal policies. It´s still to be proved their efficiency knowing that State has several other tools in order to promote the same goals associated to secondary policies, like the use of sectorial legislation, taxation or subsidies.

In my view, this should suffice to at least refrain from their expansion, particularly under centralised procurement.

Nevertheless, I think we shouldn`t regret the importance of the (possible) use of public procurement to pursue (some) secondary policies like social policies. Said this, I just want to make some telegraphic notes:

i) It´s true that the pursue of secondary policies through public procurement does not have (enough) democratic legitimacy. Still, knowing that (most) of the central purchasing bodies in Europe directly depend on central government, we can say that centralisation of public procurement is the (ideal) way to develop secondary policies because governments can directly control those bodies and the policies they pursue (in Portugal, central government can send direct instructions to the central purchasing body). The issue of democratic legitimacy is one that can provoke a huge discussion namely in the field of EU law (and the powers of the European commission…);

I strongly disagree with this approach. The issue is quite significant because the establishment of higher requirements (green, social or otherwise) in procurement than in general consumption of goods in services shows a clear regulatory/legislative double-standard that can hardly be monitored or resolved through governmental control of the central purchasing body. There is no good reason why the public sector cannot purchase goods and services legally marketed to private buyers. If the government/legislator considers that a given product or service should not be consumed for objective reasons, it needs to legislate in that way. Otherwise, this approach does not only lead to a clear democratic deficit, but also to a cross-subsidy that can go both in favour of or against the public purse / consumer purse.

ii) Public bodies are subjected to the legality principle. As so, and knowing that most European constitutions (and the TFEU) acknowledge the precaution principle in environmental issues and also the equality principle, one can recognise that secondary policies (namely social policies) should be consider by public bodies on the decision of what to buy;

Yes, but only expressed and articulated (by hard law instruments) environmental and social rules. Again, as above, there is no reason why procurement policy needs to be more cautious in environmental or social terms than the explicit and legislated environmental and social policies themselves.

iii) Your last post mentions some articles that stress that set-asides are a bad ideia. Some of those articles come from the 80’s and the 90’s, knowing that (modern) secondary policies (like the one connected with environmental and social policies) appeared mainly last decade (after Concordia Bus case, although I’m aware of previous Du Pont de Nemours case and others) and that some authors have recognised their importance in the recent past, like Arrowsmith, Kunzlik and MacCrudden (despite the fact that some may disagree with these policies). After the Concordia Bus case, the 2004 and 2014 directives, the national experiences and, mainly, the ECJ cases (like Concordia Bus, Wienstrom and Ruffert) it became clear that there was a new role to public procurement in this field;

In my view there is no new role (maybe some more regulatory space, but no new role) for secondary policies in the current rules and, in economic terms, the situation is exactly the same assessed under the studies I refer to. I agree that new empirical studies would be really useful in trying to price or measure the distortions created in EU markets at present, but I would stress that the value of proper empirical work is that it allows us to test economic theories. And, as far as I can read, there is no question that secondary/horizontal policies create economic inefficiency. The burden of proof, in empirical terms, lies on the other side.

iv) The economic crises that some European countries have been facing showed the importance of public procurement as an economic policy tool, like we saw mainly between 2009 and 2010 when the European Commission inducted member states to spend more public money is order to stabilise economy;

I partially agree, in that there is an economic role to be plaid by public procurement as a macroeconomic policy. However, that is a decision on the level of expenditure and, possibly, on areas of priority. However, that has nothing to do with what should be bought or how. I develop these issues distinguishing the different economic roles of procurement in my book and I stick to that [A Sanchez Graells, Public Procurement and the EU Competition Rules, 2nd edn (Oxford, Hart, 2015) 52-56].

v) In fact, market failures must be covered by state and they can be through multiple ways (depending on how efficient they prove to be), namely by regulation through contract (but sometimes, for sure, not directly through public procurement but through other instruments such as sectorial legislation, taxes or subsidies).

Not sure about this point. However, market failures are not the only ones that concern procurement, which should also be wary of regulatory or government failures. Capture or gold-plating by the central purchasing body is at least equally worrying.

vi) In the EU law, secondary policies appeared in a shy way with the 2004 directives and they are one of the main causes of the 2014 directives so we can’t deny the will of the European legislator in this matter;

Yes, but that does not mean we need to acritically accept that whatever the legislator wants to do is in the society's best interest. There are too many theoretical and historical objections to list them here.

vii) If we exclude the use of secondary policies, we are comparing, at the end, public procurement with private procurement. Still, public procurement must follow public interest and this one is not always connected with an idea of the lowest price or efficiency (or an idea of simplification of public procurement).

I disagree. We are just disentangling the regulatory/public power of deciding what to buy from the economic mechanism of procurement, which should be concerned with how to buy that in the most efficient way.

Nevertheless, even the criteria of the lowest price can be used to promote secondary policies (e.g. through technical specifications or the use of eco-labels) and, on the other hand, by choosing the most economic advantageous proposal, public bodies can promote secondary policies even without a clear legal base, so every guidance we can give in this area will be helpful;

Guidance may or may not be helpful. I agree that secondary policies could permeate different parts of the procurement cycle. However, the rules on technical specifications are much more stringent than those on award criteria in terms of accepting equivalent solutions and limiting formal restrictions to participation. Hence, I would much rather see green procurement limited to technical specifications and social clauses to contract compliance requirements (both of which have been limited in Dutch coffee and Bundesdruckerei) than in award criteria, where the scenario is much less streamlined.

viii) We know that, at the end, secondary policies can determine that prices get higher for public bodies. Still, the goal of public procurement is not only to assure value for money but also to promote public interest and this one can allow public bodies to buy in a more expensive way in order to promote, v.g., social policies.

This is very contentious. I completely disagree. Arrowsmith (in mild terms) and Kunzlik (in more enthusiastic terms) may agree with you. Here is a summary of the academic "conversation" we have been having for a while.

ix) Public interest (and European interest) has raised environmental policy to one transversal European policy (and the ECJ has said that) that must be included in public procurement concerns (and it was not in the past). The ECJ has said the same about social policies, namely in the Viking case;

That sounds like a bit of a simplification to me, particularly because the CJEU has always been stressing the need to comply with enacted secondary rules, rather than with policies. In any case, the opposition to secondary policies is not to be extended to procuring goods or services in compliance with the applicable legislation, which is an altogether different discussion.

x) I´m aware that the use of secondary policies may cause distortions in the market (and in competition). But public procurement is not concerned just with the competition principle (knowing that this one has been raising its importance after FENIN-SELEX ECJ cases and the new directives). Here, proportionality principle may help to balance competition principle with the pursue of secondary policies connected with the public interest. In some cases, it might be necessary to exclude some competitors that act in the same relevant market (e.g. State can exclude competitors that sell cars that pollute excessively or sellers of inefficient lamps) in order to promote secondary policies, namely promoting a change in technology that its consider to be needed according to the public interest.

I disagree. If the State does not want excessively polluting cars, it needs to legislate against them. If it is legal to sell those cars, there is no justification for an exclusion of the offeror from public procurement. Secondary policies cannot be a fix for the inability to legislate appropriately.

xi) In the field of secondary policies, the use of soft law is a way to, step by step, get to hard law and sometimes it has a fundamental role in order to allow the operators to understand the functioning of hard law. For example, competition law wouldn`t really be comprehensive without soft law (knowing that, in most of the times, it follows ECJ case law) even if, sometimes, the road gets away from soft law (e.g. what happens with the relevant market definition and the modern economic approach to merger control). We can also see the same use of soft law in tax law and I think we shouldn`t deny it`s value in the interpretation and development of public procurement law in the future.

If we don´t have soft law, the discretionary power of public bodies would be even bigger knowing that the use of secondary policies is allowed in the 2014 directives in general terms. As so, soft law can have a role in order to make more clear the use of secondary policies (and the situations where they can´t be used) although we are aware of the risks concerning the frontier between hard law and soft law (that were already raised by the ECJ);

I disagree with this, particularly in the competition field. Soft law is an asymmetrical lye we tell ourselves simply to allow regulation to be developed below the radar screens. My more developed views are available at A Sanchez-Graells, Soft Law and the Private Enforcement of the EU Competition Rules (July 2010)].

xii) The use of social policies through public procurement was, in some countries, a case of success in the past (v.g. USA; UK; Canada; South Africa; Malasia) so we shouldn`t throw the possible use of it immediately away;

I remain to be presented with any evidence about the success of any of those policies in any of those jurisdictions.

Like I said, this is just a short reaction to your post, without quoting any article or book to support me, that I’m sending you with friendship and admiration. I really don`t have a close view on this issue but I think (and I agree with what you say on your blog) that, concerning secondary policies, we won`t go back after 2014 directives. As so, operators will need guidance in this matter in the future.

Well, it is certainly an area where we will continue holding academic debates. :)

Postscript: Some further thoughts by Prof. Cunha Rodrigues

i) You say that secondary policies, at the end, can produce "a cross-subsidy that can go both in favour of or against the public purse / consumer purse." I think that this idea is stick to one of economic efficiency that is not necessarily linked to public interest. Sometimes, it`s necessary to pay more (public purse / consumer purse) in order to get a superior social outcome or to have a change in technology so cross-subsidy can have a positive effect to tax payer in a near future (namely when we prove that the outcome is more efficient if compared with other public tools).

Promoting social policies buying to companies that employ handicapped persons may not satisfy economic efficiency but it will meet public interest and satisfy public procurement goals. Another example: every time technology moves forward, prices get higher at the beginning so State, through public procurement, can have a role in helping to develop that technology and getting prices to be cheaper, namely by buying those products. That happened, in several countries, for essence when some public bodies decide to buy electric cars (and, in those cases, I think that competition would be more distorted if we exclude from the market inefficient cars through hard law rather than excluding them through public procurement).

ii) You mentioned that “secondary policies cannot be a fix for the inability to legislate appropriately”. I think that this idea, at the end, would translate to hard law the decision to exclude some (inefficient) products from the market what might agravate the effect of distorting competition because: a) it wouldn´t allow private parties to decide what to buy; b) it would exclude private producers from the market, causing an even bigger distortion of competition than the one (eventually) caused by using secondary policies through public procurement.

This is somehow an idea similar to what happens in competition law where, in some cases, R&D can justify antitrust behavior (along with others conditions, for sure, according to article 101.º, n.º 3 of the TFEU). In both cases, one can say that competition principle or an idea of economic efficiency doesn`t necessary prevail. Naturally this example can’t be understood in cases where public procurement comes along with monopsony power (and I fully agree with you that the possible application of article 102.º of the TFUE can be wider, in the future, even knowing FENIN and SELEX cases, because of the role that central purchasing bodies can and will have under 2014 directives).

Rules applicable to communication under Reg. 22 Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (II)

Following yesterday's discussion (on Pedro's blog and here) on the first part of reg.22 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015), we are bound to continue the assessment of the transposition of the rules of Article 22 of Directive 2014/24 as electronic communications are concerned (Pedro's further views are available here). I will pick up on the issue of oral communications, which Pedro discussed extensively yesterday and on which he raised some important issues concerning equality, non-discrimination and traceability of the communication. He also mentioned in passing the difficulties derived from language barriers to communication (oral or otherwise), which are of course the elephant in the room.

Reg.22(8) to (10) PCR2015 deals with the novelty of an (express) authorisation to carry on oral communications. Reg.22(8) establishes the authorisation, which covers communications other than those concerning the essential elements of a procurement procedure, provided that the content of the oral communication is documented to a sufficient degree. Reg.22(9) then determines what is not an essential element of the procedure, or rectius, indicates that the essential elements of a procurement procedure include the procurement documents, requests to participate, confirmations of interest and tenders. Reg.22(10) also makes the record-creation and record-keeping requirements more specific by stressing that oral communications with tenderers which could have a substantial impact on the content and assessment of the tenders shall be documented to a sufficient extent and by appropriate means, such as written or audio records or summaries of the main elements of the communication.

Looking at the provisions as a whole, I struggle to see how oral communications can actually be used properly. There are certain things that should not be done orally, such as providing clarification on the tender documents or requirements, or accepting clarifications on the documents or tenders submitted by bidders. Equally, it is hard to see how negotiation can be carried out orally when, under reg.22(9) PCR2015, the tenders themselves are an essential element of the procedure on which oral communications are not allowed. Of course, this does not square with the rule in reg.22(10) PCR2015, which aims to set a minimum threshold (or expectation) of record-creation when negotiations are conducted if they could have a substantial impact on the content and assessment of the tenders. All in all, I find this set of rules very confusing and internally contradictory, and I would be £0.05 to any takers that there will be significant litigation in the near future--that is, if contracting authorities dare to use oral communications to any significant degree.

Use of tools and devices not generally available

Reg.22(13) to (15) deal with the issue of means of electronic communication not generally available and builds an exception to the general rule established by reg.22(2) PCR2015. In order to allow contracting authorities to require the use of tools and devices which are not generally available, the regulation demands that that the contracting authorities offer suitable alternative means of access. These are then further specified in reg.22(14), which offers three alternative ways of ensuring alternative means of access: (a) offer unrestricted and full direct access free of charge by electronic means to the tools and devices concerned from the date of publication of the call for competition or from the date when the invitation to confirm interest is sent [in which case the further rules of reg.22(15) need to be respected]; (b) ensure that tenderers having no access to the tools and devices concerned, or no possibility of obtaining them within the relevant time limits, provided that the lack of access is not attributable to the tenderer concerned, may access the procurement procedure through the use of provisional tokens made available free of charge online; or (c) support an alternative channel for electronic submission of tenders.

Given that the last option is the only one likely not to impose a cost on the contracting authority and given that it avoids having to enter into the licences and authorisations that one would expect under options (a) and (b), my view is that most contracting authorities that insist on the use of means of communication not generally available will also end up supporting an alternative channel for electronic submission of tenders. This creates the same difficulties that we witnessed in the past (only?) regarding technical specifications set according to standards and the mandatory requirement to accept functionally equivalent solutions. Moreover, this creates significant issues of justification of the use of not generally available means of communication. If the alternative channels (supported or otherwise) work, what is the reason not to use them? Consequently, this is another area where the set of rules does not seem to make much internal sense and the availability of funds to sponsor use of not generally available means of communication (or its lack) may end up deactivating the provision in any case.

Technical requirements, security requirements and electronic signatures

Reg.22(16) to (21) set out rather precise requirements concerning the technical and security-related features of the electronic means of communication to be used, as well as specific rules concerning the use of electronic signatures. To be honest, the technicalities may create issues that I fail to see, but these requirements seem relatively uncomplicated to me. It is worth stressing that in determining the security level applicable to the electronic communications, contracting authorities are required to consider the need for proportionality between the expected benefits of any particular security requirements and the costs, burdens and obligations which those requirements may impose on economic operators. This seems like a reasonable requirement but, once more, effectively putting it in practice may be complicated, particularly if judicial review of that type of decision is based on a formal assessment of the contracting authority's decision.

CJEU offers clarification on identification and assessment of conflicts of interest in public procurement (C-538/13)

In its Judgment in eVigilo, C-538/13, EU:C:2015:166, the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU) has offered very much needed guidance on the assessment of conflicts of interest in public procurement, as well as the degree of forcefulness with which contracting authorities must tackle such important issue. 

Its guidance will be very relevant in the interpretation and application of Article 24 of Directive 2014/24 on conflicts of interest, as well as the related provision on exclusion of economic operators affected by conflicts of interest [art 57(4)(e) dir 2014/24]. Thus, the eVigilo Judgment and the CJEU's reasoning deserve some close analysis.

Concerning the issue of conflict of interest (there were others to be addressed, particularly regarding the time limits for the challenge of a procurement decision), it is worth highlighting that eVigilo challenged the award on the basis of a bias of the experts who evaluated the tenders due to the existence of professional relations between them and the specialists referred to in the winning tender. 

More specifically, eVigilo claimed that the specialists referred to in the tender submitted by the successful tenderers were colleagues at the Technical University of Kaunas (Kauno technologijos universitetas) of three of the six experts of the contracting authority who drew up the tender documents and evaluated the tenders. In its view, this was sufficient to strike the award decision down.

This is a situation that, in my view, would now be clearly covered by Art 24 Dir 2014/24 (not applicable to the conflict time-wise), whereby "conflicts of interest shall at least cover any situation where staff members of the contracting authority or of a procurement service provider acting on behalf of the contracting authority who are involved in the conduct of the procurement procedure or may influence the outcome of that procedure have, directly or indirectly, a financial, economic or other personal interest which might be perceived to compromise their impartiality and independence in the context of the procurement procedure" (emphasis added). 

Hence, the CJEU's assessment of the claim is highly relevant. After reiterating its case law on the principles of equality, non-discrimination and transparency, and stressing that "[u]nder the principle of equal treatment as between tenderers, the aim of which is to promote the development of healthy and effective competition between undertakings taking part in a public procurement procedure, all tenderers must be afforded equality of opportunity", the CJEU considered that
37 The finding of bias on the part of an expert requires in particular the assessment of facts and evidence that comes within the competence of the contracting authorities and the administrative or judicial control authorities.
38 It should be pointed out that neither Directive 89/665 nor Directive 2004/18 contains specific provisions in that regard
[and, it is worth adding, Directive 2014/24 does not contain any specific procedural rules as to how to assess these issues either].
39 The Court has consistently held that, in the absence of EU rules governing the matter, it is for every Member State to lay down the detailed rules of administrative and judicial procedures for safeguarding rights which individuals derive from EU law. Those detailed procedural rules must, however, be no less favourable than those governing similar domestic actions (principle of equivalence) and must not render impossible in practice or excessively difficult the exercise of rights conferred by EU law (principle of effectiveness) (see judgment in Club Hotel Loutraki and Others, C‑145/08 et C‑149/08, EU:C:2010:247, paragraph 74 and the case-law cited).
40 In particular, the detailed procedural rules governing the remedies intended to protect rights conferred by EU law on candidates and tenderers harmed by decisions of contracting authorities must not compromise the effectiveness of Directive 89/665 (see judgment in Uniplex (UK), C‑406/08, EU:C:2010:45, paragraph 27 and case-law cited).
41 It is not, as a general rule, contrary to those principles for an expert’s bias to be established in a Member State solely on the basis of an objective situation in order to prevent any risk that the public contracting authority could be guided by considerations unrelated to the contract in question and liable, by virtue of that fact alone, to give preference to one tenderer.
42 Concerning the rules on evidence in that regard, it should be pointed out that ... the contracting authorities are to treat economic operators equally and non-discriminatorily and to act in a transparent way. It follows that they are assigned an active role in the application of those principles of public procurement.
43 Since that duty relates to the very essence of the public procurement directives (see judgment in Michaniki, C‑213/07, EU:C:2008:731, paragraph 45), it follows that the contracting authority is, at all events, required to determine whether any conflicts of interests exist and to take appropriate measures in order to prevent and detect conflicts of interests and remedy them. It would be incompatible with that active role for the applicant to bear the burden of proving, in the context of the appeal proceedings, that the experts appointed by the contracting authority were in fact biased. Such an outcome would also be contrary to the principle of effectiveness and the requirement of an effective remedy ... in light, in particular, of the fact that a tenderer is not, in general, in a position to have access to information and evidence allowing him to prove such bias.
44 Thus, if the unsuccessful tenderer presents objective evidence calling into question the impartiality of one of the contracting authority’s experts, it is for that contracting authority to examine all the relevant circumstances having led to the adoption of the decision relating to the award of the contract in order to prevent and detect conflicts of interests and remedy them, including, where appropriate, requesting the parties to provide certain information and evidence.
45 Evidence such as the claims in the main proceedings relating to the connections between the experts appointed by the contracting authority and the specialists of the undertakings awarded the contract, in particular, the fact that those persons work together in the same university, belong to the same research group or have relationships of employer and employee within that university, if proved to be true, constitutes such objective evidence as must lead to a thorough examination by the contracting authority or, as the case may be, by the administrative or judicial control authorities.
46 Subject to compliance with the obligations under EU law, and specifically with those referred to in paragraph 43 above, the concept of ‘bias’ and the criteria for it are to be defined by national law. The same applies to the rules relating to the legal effects of possible bias. Thus, it is for national law to determine whether, and if so to what extent, the competent administrative and judicial authorities must take into account the fact that possible bias on the part of the experts had no effect on the decision to award the contract
(C-538/13, paras 37 to 46, emphasis added).
In my view, the CJEU has handed down a very straightforward Judgment that clearly favours (or, actually, imposes) a strong reaction to allegations of bias and conflict of interest, and which sets a very high threshold regarding the relevant duty of the contracting authority to investigate and to act. Ultimately, this derives from the obligation of contracting authorities to enforce the general principles of procurement (now in art 18 dir 2014/24, which includes the principle of competition) and its diligent administration implications.

The reader will allow me to submit that this is fundamentally in line with my interpretation of the rules on conflict of interest under Art 24 Dir 2014/24 as developed in Public Procurement and the EU Competition Rules, 2nd edn (Oxford, Hart, 2015) 369-373, which I reproduce below. 

Consequently, I cannot but welcome the CJEU's eVigilo Judgment and hope that Member States will take it into due account in the transposition of the rules of Dir 2014/24 into their domestic legal orders.




As a preliminary issue with potential ramifications regarding all the decisions to be adopted at the stage of evaluation of the tenders and award of the contract—although, as mentioned previously, it is also relevant in various previous phases related inter alia to the qualitative selection of tenderers—in our view, contracting authorities are under an obligation to adopt an approach to the development of these tasks that is both neutral and possibilistic. The existence of a duty of neutrality or ‘impartiality’ of procurement procedures—and, implicitly, of contracting authorities—as a specification of the principles of equal treatment, of the ensuing transparency obligation, and of the principle of competition is a clear requirement of the system envisaged in the directives,[1] and has been hinted at in the EU case law by requiring that ‘the impartiality of procurement procedures’ is ensured.[2]
The existence of such a neutrality requirement is fundamental, and the EU judicature has consistently stressed the obligation of contracting authorities to guarantee equality of opportunity of tenderers at each and every stage of the tendering procedure.[3] Importantly, it should be stressed that

Under the principle of equal treatment as between tenderers, the aim of which is to promote the development of healthy and effective competition between undertakings taking part in a public procurement procedure, all tenderers must be afforded equality of opportunity when formulating their tenders, which therefore implies that the tenders of all competitors must be subject to the same conditions (emphasis added).[4] Moreover, this ultimately rests on the clear position that a system of undistorted competition, as laid down in the Treaty, can be guaranteed only if equality of opportunity is secured as between the various economic operators.[5]

In this regard, it has been emphasised that contracting authorities are under a particular duty to avoid conflicts of interest[6] with the result that, after the discovery of such a conflict of interests between a member of the evaluation committee and one of the tenderers, the contracting authority must act with due diligence and on the basis of all the relevant information when formulating and adopting its decision on the outcome of the procedure for the award of the tender at issue in order to comply with the basic obligation of ensuring equality of opportunity.[7] This might require different reactions from the contracting authority, depending on the circumstances of the case, but should always be oriented towards preventing instances of discriminationie, not favouring, or discriminating against, a tenderer as a result of the bias of the member of the evaluation committee.[8] Therefore, there should be no doubt as to the neutrality requirements in the conduct of the evaluation of tenders and award of public contracts. This is now particularly clear in light of the provisions in article 24 of Directive 2014/24, which expressly requires that Member States ensure that contracting authorities take appropriate measures to effectively prevent, identify and remedy conflicts of interest arising in the conduct of procurement procedures so as to avoid any distortion of competition and to ensure equal treatment of all economic operators.[9] This measure is complemented by the new ground for exclusion of economic operators in clonflict of interest (as discussed above §II.A.vii). Consequently, under the 2014 rules, contracting authorities are under a very clear mandate to detect, investigate and effectively tackle conflicts of interest.
As regards the adoption of a ‘possibilistic’ or anti-formalistic approach—oriented towards maintaining the maximum possible degree of competition by avoiding the rejection of offers on the basis of too formal and/or automatic rejection criteria—it is important to underline that the relevant case law has already offered some guidance that points in this direction by stressing that ‘the guarantees conferred by the European Union legal order in administrative proceedings include, in particular, the principle of good administration, involving the duty of the competent institution to examine carefully and impartially all the relevant aspects of the individual case’ (emphasis added)[10]—which, in the case of public procurement, should be interpreted as requiring contracting authorities to exercise due care in the evaluation of the bids submitted by tenderers.[11] To be sure, the obligation of contracting authorities to review the bids for possible mistakes and to contact tenderers to seek for correction is limited as a mandate of the principle of non-discrimination (below §II.B.ix); but the scope for clarification of the tenders and for the establishment of rules allowing for a flexible treatment of formally non-fully compliant bids (on this, below §II.B.iv), support the adoption of a possibilistic approach towards the evaluation of bids as a specification or particularisation of the duty of due care or diligent administration that is required of contracting authorities.
In this regard, as reasoned by EU case law, the evaluating team is under an obligation to conduct the revision of the bids in accordance with the principle of good administration and is, consequently, under an obligation to exercise the power to ask for additional information in circumstances where the clarification of a tender is clearly both practically possible and necessary, and as long as the exercise of that duty to seek clarification is in accordance with the principle of equal treatment.[12] It is submitted that this means that the evaluating team is to adopt an anti-formalistic approach that renders the effective appraisal of the tenders possible—regardless of minor deficiencies, ambiguities or apparent mistakes. Indeed, as stressed by the jurisprudence, in cases where the terms of a tender themselves and the surrounding circumstances known to the authority indicate that the ambiguity probably has a simple explanation and can be easily resolved, then, in principle, it is contrary to the requirements of good administration for an evaluation committee to reject the tender without exercising its power to seek clarification. A decision to reject a tender in such circumstances is, consequently, liable to be vitiated by a manifest error of assessment on the part of the institution in the exercise of that power,[13] and could result in an unnecessary restriction of competition. In that regard, it should be taken into consideration that

it is also essential, in the interests of legal certainty, that the contracting authority should be able to ascertain precisely what a tender offer means and, in particular, whether it complies with the conditions set out in the specifications. Thus, where a tender is ambiguous and it is not possible for the contracting authority to establish, swiftly and efficiently, what it actually means, that authority has no choice but to reject that tender (emphasis added).[14]

Therefore, in a nutshell, contracting authorities should ensure that the evaluation of bids leading to the award of the contract is based on the substance of the tenders, adopting a possibilistic or anti-formalist approach that excludes purely formal decisions that restrict competition unnecessarily; subject, always, to guaranteeing compliance with the principle of equal treatment. In that vein, it is important to stress that the duty of good administration does not go so far as to require the evaluation team to seek clarification in every case where a tender is ambiguously drafted.[15] Particularly as regards calculations and other possible non-obvious clerical mistakes, the duty of good administration is considerably more restricted and the evaluation team’s diligence only requires that clarification be sought in the face of obvious errors that should have been detected by the purchasing agency when assessing the bid.[16] This is so particularly because the presence of non-obvious errors and their subsequent amendment or correction might result in breaches of the principle of equal treatment.[17] Therefore, as general criteria, it seems that the relevant case law intends to favour the possibilistic approach hereby advanced, subject to two restrictions: i) that it does not breach the principle of equal treatment (ie, that it does not jeopardise the neutrality of the evaluation of tenders), and ii) that it does not require the contracting authority to develop special efforts to identify errors or insufficiencies in the tenders that do not arise from a diligent and regular evaluation.
Therefore, it is submitted that contracting authorities should develop the activities of evaluation of bids and award of the contract on the basis of such a neutral and possibilistic approach—which must be aimed at trying not to restrict competition on the basis of considerations that are too formal (ie, effectively to appraise which is the tender that actually or in substance offers the best conditions, regardless of minor formal defects or non-fulfilment of immaterial requirements) and, at the same time, ensuring compliance with the principle of non-discrimination and the ensuing transparency obligation.


[1] In this regard, it should be stressed that the principles of non-discrimination and competition present close links; see above ch 5 §IV.A, with references to the relevant case law.
[2] Case C-324/98 Telaustria and Telefonadress [2000] ECR I-10745 62. See also H-J Prieβ, ‘Distortions of Competition in Tender Proceedings … and the Involvement of Project Consultants’ (2002) 156.
[3] See: Case C-496/99 P Succhi di Frutta [2004] ECR I-3801 108. See also Case T-406/06 Evropaïki Dynamiki (CITL) [2008] ECR II-247 83; Joined Cases T-376/05 and T-383/05 TEA–CEGOS [2006] ECR II-205 76; Case T-160/03 AFCon Management Consultants [2005] ECR II-981 75; and Case T-145/98 ADT Projekt [2000] ECR II-387 164.
[4] Case T-345/03 Evropaïki Dynamiki v Commission (CORDIS) [2008] ECR II-341 143; and Case T-86/09 Evropaïki Dynamiki v Commission [2011] ECR II-309 61.
[5] Case C-202/88 France v Commission [1991] ECR I-1223 51; Case C-462/99 Connect Austria [2003] ECR I-5197 83; and Case T-250/05 Evropaïki Dynamiki (OPOCE) [2007] ECR II-85 46.
[6] As now emphasised in recital (16) of Directive 2014/24: ‘Contracting authorities should make use of all possible means at their disposal under national law in order to prevent distortions in public procurement procedures stemming from conflicts of interest. This could include procedures to identify, prevent and remedy conflicts of interests.’
[7] Case T-160/03 AFCon Management Consultants [2005] ECR II-981 75; and, by analogy, Case T-231/97 New Europe Consulting [1999] ECR II-2403 41. Recently, see Case T-297/05 IPK International v Commission [2011] ECR II-1859 122.
[8] For an overview of evaluating teams regulation and practice in the US—which focus on similar concerns—see SW Feldman, ‘Agency Evaluators in Negotiated Acquisitions’ (1991–1992) 21 Public Contract Law Journal 279; and DI Gordon, ‘Organizational Conflict of Interest: A Growing Integrity Challenge’ (2005–2006) 35 Public Contract Law Journal 25.
[9] Arrowsmith (n 28) 1295–96. Generally, see P Lascoumes, ‘Condemning corruption and tolerating conflicts of interest’, in JB Auby, E Breen and T Perroud (eds), Corruption and Conflicts of Interest: A Comparative Law Approach, Studies in Comparative Law and Legal Culture (Cheltenham, Edgar Elgar, 2014) 67–84. See also DI Gordon and G Racca, ‘Integrity Challenges in the EU and U.S. Procurement Systems’, in G M Racca and C R Yukins (eds), Integrity and Efficiency in Sustainable Public Contracts (Brussels, Bruylant, 2014) 117–46.
[10] Case T-236/09 Evropaïki Dynamiki v Commission [2012] pub. electr. EU:T:2012:127 45; and Joined Cases T-376/05 and T-383/05 TEA–CEGOS [2006] ECR II-205 76.
[11] ibid.
[12] See: Case T-211/02 Tideland Signal [2002] ECR II-3781 37–38, and cited case law. See also C-599/10 Slovensko [2011] ECR I-10873 and Case C-336/12 Manova [2013] pub. electr. EU:C:2013:647.
[13]  Case T-211/02 Tideland Signal [2002] ECR II-3781 37–38; Case T-63/06 Evropaïki Dynamiki v OEDT [2010] ECR II-177 98; Case T-195/08 Antwerpse Bouwwerken v Commission [2009] ECR II-4439 56; Case T-554/08 Evropaïki Dynamiki v Commission [2012] pub. electr. EU:T:2012:194 56; and Case T-553/11 European Dynamics Luxembourg v ECB [2014] pub. electr. EU:T:2014:275 300.
[14] Case T-211/02 Tideland Signal [2002] ECR II-3781 34; Case T-63/06 Evropaïki Dynamiki v OEDT [2010] ECR II-177 98; and Case T-8/09 Dredging International and Ondernemingen Jan de Nul v EMSA [2011] ECR II-6123 71.
[15] See: Case T-211/02 Tideland Signal [2002] ECR II-3781 37 ab initio.
[16] See: Case T-495/04 Belfass [2008] ECR II-781 65–71.
[17] Case T-19/95 Adia Interim [1996] ECR II-321 43–49. Similarly, Case T-169/00 Esedra [2002] ECR II-609 49; and Case T-195/05 Deloitte Business Advisory [2007] ECR II-871 102.

Rules applicable to communication under Reg. 22 Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (I)

Reg.22 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) deals with the rules applicable to communication and transposes the requirements of Article 22 of Directive 2014/24. It introduces important novelties in terms of electronic communications and includes specific safeguards intended to prevent technological exclusion and gold-plating. 

The comment to this reg.22 PCR2015 would take too long to be done at once, so Pedro and I have decided to split it in three parts. We discuss paragraphs 1-12 today, and two more entries will follow.

General rules applicable to communication

(A) As a point of departure, reg.22(1) PCR2015 establishes that all communications shall be performed using electronic means of communication in accordance with the requirements of that regulation. 

(B) However, this general rule is riddled with exceptions that allow contracting authorities not to require the use of electronic means of communication, such as:
  1.  Specific circumstances foreseen in reg.22(3) PCR2015, where it is accepted that the use of electronic means of communication would be either impracticable or counterproductive from a technical perspective, such as where : (a) due to the specialised nature of the procurement, the use of electronic means of communication would require specific tools, devices or file formats that are not generally available or supported by generally available applications; (b) the applications supporting file formats that are suitable for the description of the tenders use file formats that cannot be handled by any other open or generally available applications or are under a proprietary licensing scheme and cannot be made available for downloading or remote use by the contracting authority; (c) the use of electronic means of communication would require specialised office equipment that is not generally available to contracting authorities; or (d) the procurement documents require the submission of physical or scale models which cannot be transmitted using electronic means.
  2. Specific circumstances established in reg.22(5) PCR2015, where the use of means of communication other than electronic means is necessary either (a) because of a breach of security of the electronic means of communication, or (b) for the protection of information of a particularly sensitive nature requiring such a high level of protection that it cannot be properly ensured by using electronic tools and devices that are either generally available to economic operators or can be made available to them by alternative means of access[see reg.22(14) PCR2015].

In the first case, the exceptions under reg.22(3) PCR2015 are complemented with two additional rules. On the one hand, where contracting authorities require other than electronic means of communication  in the submission process, they shall indicate in a reg.84(1) report the reasons for that requirement [as per reg.22(6) PCR2015]. This suggests that contracting authorities do not have a fully-free choice and, in any case, such decision is open to judicial review.

And, on the other hand, the exception must not be understood as an all or nothing concerning electronic means of communication, since reg.22(4) PCR2015 determines that where those are not used, communication shall be carried out by post or by other suitable carrier, or by a combination thereof.  Consequently, under proportionality, the limitation of use of electronic communication means should only be completely excluded where they are absolutely unfit for a specific (and probably rather out of the ordinary) procurement process.

(C) Reg.22 PCR2015 establishes two general requirements in the management of electronic communications that are worth stressing. 

First, contracting authorities shall ensure that the integrity of data and the confidentiality of tenders and requests to participate are preserved in all communication, exchange and storage of information [reg.22(11) PCR2015]. This should be put in relation to reg.21 PCR2015 on confidentiality (see comments here and here). In my view, the difficulty with this rule is that it seems to impose an objective obligation on contracting authorities "shall ensure" rather than a best effort/reasonable means obligation, which can trigger important issues of liability in tort should the confidentiality of communications be jeopardised (or hacked) at any specific point in time. 

Consequently, a clarification on the level of liability imposed on the contracting authorities would reduce their incentives to resort to the exceptions under reg.22(5) PCR2015. On that note, it is important to stress that, however, contracting authorities do not seem to have a fully-free choice, as reg.22(7) PCR2015 clearly sets out that they shall indicate in a reg.84(1) report the reasons why the use of means of communication other than electronic means has been considered necessary--which, in my view, is again open to judicial review.

Secondly, in order to avoid an important issue of time advantages or time shifting, reg.22(12) PCR2015 clarifies that contracting authorities shall examine the content of tenders and requests to participate only after the time limit set for submitting them has expired. This will require the implementation of additional security measures that allow for a time-related (and manipulation-related) audit of the procurement process. However, the discussion on technical security measures is best left for the discussion of paras 16 and ff of reg.22 PCR2015).


(D) Finally and in order to avoid technological barriers derived from the use of electronic communications, reg.22(2) PCR2015 determines that the tools and devices to be used and their technical characteristics shall be non-discriminatory, generally available and interoperable with the information and communication technology products in general use and shall not restrict economic operators’ access to the procurement procedure [for some previous discussion, see M Varney, ‘E-Procurement—current law and future challenges’ (2011) 12(2) ERA Forum 185–204].

This comes to set a requirement of technological neutrality that must be welcome in general terms. The only exception to this rule  is established in reg.22(13) PCR2015, which allows contracting authorities to require the use of tools and devices which are not generally available provided they offer suitable alternative means of access--and this is further regulated in reg.22(14) and ff PCR2015, which will be discussed tomorrow.

Confidentiality under Reg. 21 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

As Pedro analysed yesterday (with a rebuttal based on this entry, which I mention below*), reg.21(1) of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) establishes confidentiality duties on the contracting authorities, so that they shall not disclose information forwarded by an economic operator and designated by that economic operator as confidential, including, but not limited to, technical or trade secrets and the confidential aspects of tenders. 

Reg.21(2) sets some restrictions in order to allow for certain minimal publicity and transparency to take place, as well as to coordinate these provisions with rules on freedom of information and access to public documents; and, finally, reg.21(3) allows contracting authorities to impose confidentiality duties on candidates and tenderers aimed at protecting the confidential nature of information which the contracting authorities make available throughout the procurement procedure. This is a very close transposition (with some good reordering) of the rules in Art 21 of Directive 2014/24.

Generally, this is a set of rules aimed at striking a balance between transparency (a general principle of procurement, see reg.18 PCR2015) and the protection of sensitive commercial or official information, and needs to be complemented with the further rules in reg.55(3) PCR2015 on debriefing of disappointed tenderers (to be commented in due course). 

This is an area where the case law of the CJEU has stressed the relevance of protection of confidential information and provided some general guidance on how to balance competing needs; see Varec, C-450/06, EU:C:2008:91 and K von Papp, Case C-450/06, 'Varec SA v. Belgian State, judgment of the Court (Third Chamber) of 14 February 2008, [2008] ECR I-58' (2009) 46 Common Market Law Review 991–1000].
In my view, the most significant difficulties that such a balance entails concern the impact of transparency on competition in public procurement markets. As clearly put by the OECD:The formal rules governing public procurement can make communication among rivals easier, promoting collusion among bidders. While collusion can emerge in both procurement and “ordinary” markets, procurement regulations may facilitate collusive arrangements’ [OECD, Public Procurement: Role of Competition Authorities (2007) 7].

The risk for a strategic use of access to confidential information (through debriefing processes, or otherwise) seems at least twofold. On the one hand, tenderers could try to gain access to confidential information which could be used later to compete unfairly with the affected tenderers. On the other hand, excessive disclosure of information can increase market transparency and be used as a means to collude or to reinforce collusion by tenderers [generally, see RC Marshall and LM Marx, The Economics of Collusion. Cartels and Bidding Rings (London, MIT Press, 2012); and SE Weishaar, Cartels, Competition and Public Procurement. Law and Economics Approaches to Bid Rigging (Cheltenham, Edgar Elgar, 2013); see also A Heimler, ‘Cartels in public procurement’ (2012) 8(4) Journal of Competition Law & Economics 849–62].

Indeed, the fact that public procurement rules increase the likelihood of collusion among bidders has been convincingly proven in economic literature, and has also been stressed for a long time by legal doctrine. It is out of question that, under most common market conditions, procurement regulations significantly increase the transparency of the market and facilitate collusion among bidders through repeated interaction [see WE Kovacic et al, ‘Bidding Rings and the Design of Anti-Collusive Measures for Auctions and Procurements’ in N Dimitri et al (eds), Handbook of Procurement (Cambridge, CUP, 2006) 381, 402; and C Estevan de Quesada, ‘Competition and transparency in public procurement markets’ (2014) 23 Public Procurement Law Review 229].

Therefore, rules on disclosure of information and their implementation by contracting authorities should take into account their potentially restrictive or distortive effects on competition [for discussion, see A Sanchez Graells, The Difficult Balance between Transparency and Competition in Public Procurement: Some Recent Trends in the Case Law of the European Courts and a Look at the New Directives (University of Leicester School of Law Research Paper No. 13-11, 2013) and here]. 

Indeed, in the exercise of the discretion that contracting authorities retain in relation to confidentiality, and as a mandate of the principle of competition [reg.18(1) PCR2015], contracting authorities are bound to restrict the disclosure of information given to tenderers to prevent instances of subsequent unfair competition or collusion—and, in order to do that properly, must identify and properly justify the negative effects which the withholding of the information seeks to avoid [see VIP Car Solutions, T-89/07, EU:T:2009:163]. Hence, I would like to see a refined and intense use of reg.21 PCR2015 in the future.

(*) [Postscript] In his rebuttal, Pedro offers some interesting diverging thoughts and some of the links he builds between openness/liquidity of markets and transparency are worth thinking about. Of course, each market setting would require fine-tuned, granular transparency solutions. I struggle to see how in most market situations of more transparency to cure the diseases of transparency could work, but this is definitely an issue where a controlled experiment would be needed, as he rightly pointed out in twitter.

However, I fundamentally disagree with his claim that "Avoiding collusion is not an end in itself and a wider view of other competition-impacting aspects needs to be taken into equation", or at least with the first part. Avoiding collusion must be an end in itself, regardless of other competition impacts. Not least, because it is hard to see how the adequate reduction of transparency (ie not of contract opportunities, which I never challenged, but of contract results or procurement outputs) could generate a negative impact on competition. 

Avoiding collusion is, in my view, an end in itself and an important one. It must not be achieved at any cost, true. However, the fact that most competition authorities are prioritising enforcement of anti-cartel provisions in procurement markets is a strong indicator of the pervasiveness of bid rigging and the (not only economic) relevance of getting rid of it, or minimising it. In any case, this is an area where Pedro and I share a research interest, so I would expect further developments in the coming months.

Reserved contracts under Reg.20 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg.20 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) follows very closely Art 20 of Directive 2014/24 and creates a special regime of reserved contracts for sheltered workshops and sheltered employment programmes for the integration of disabled or disadvantaged persons that represents the European version of the US set-asides for specific types of undertakings (which is linked to the issue of reservation of contracts to specific categories of undertakings under reg.77 PCR2015, as will be discussed in due course).

Under reg.20 PCR2015, contracting authorities may reserve the right to participate in public procurement procedures to sheltered workshops and economic operators whose main aim is the social and professional integration of disabled or disadvantaged persons or may provide for such contracts to be performed in the context of sheltered employment programmes, provided that at least 30 % of the employees of those workshops, economic operators or programmes are disabled or disadvantaged workers. There is nothing to say from the perspective of the implementation of EU rules in the UK.

In my view, though, it is worth stressing that procurement set-asides are always a bad idea. As I develop in further detail elsewhere [see A Sanchez Graells, Public procurement and the EU competition rules, 2nd edn (Oxford, Hart, 2015) 100ff], their effectiveness should be questioned given the structural shortcomings of this regulatory instrument [see DE Black, ‘An Evaluation of Federal Contract Set-Aside Goals in Reducing Socioeconomic Discrimination’ (1986–1987) 20 National Contract Management Journal 87, 93–97; ibid, ‘Socioeconomic Contract Goal Setting within the Department of Defense: Promises Still Unfulfilled’ (1988–1989) 22 National Contract Management Journal 67; and TA Denes, ‘Do Small Business Set-Asides Increase the Cost of Government Contracting?’ (1997) 57 Public Administration Review 441]. 

Consequently, it would have been desirable for the UK to forgo that option under Dir 2014/24 and not implement this possibility under reg.20 PCR2015. However, the approach has been the opposite, and the goal has always been to maximise this flexibility [see Cabinet Office, Consultation Document on the UK Transposition of new EU Procurement Directives (2014) 13]. This is not only the approach in the UK--see eg the situation in Germany as described by E Sarter, D Sack & S Fuchs, Public Procurement as Social Policy? An introduction to social criteria in public procurement in Germany (2014) Universität Bielefeld Working Paper Series on Comparative Governance No. 1. 

In my view, this general approach should be lamented, as it creates significant losses of effectiveness in the procurement system itself and it is highly doubtful that the ultimate social policy goals are achieved--either at all, or at an efficient cost for society. Of course, this is a politically incorrect approach to the issue of social considerations into public procurement, and one that can hardly be presented to EU and domestic decision-makers, so reg.20 PCR2015 is highly likely to be intensely used.

Economic operators under Reg.19 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg.19 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) is concerned with economic operators and groups of economic operators, and transposes the rules in Art 19 of Directive 2014/24 with very minor drafting variations. The rules under reg.19 PCR2015 are grouped into two subheadings. Regs.19(1) and (2) are concerned with individual economic operators. Regs.19(3) to (6) are concerned with groups of economic operators.

Economic operators

Under reg.19(1) PCR2015, contracting authorities cannot prevent the participation of economic operators in the tender for service contracts solely on the ground that, under the law England and Wales, they would be required to be either natural or legal persons--always provided that the economic operator is entitled to provide the relevant service under the law of the Member State in which it is established. This is reminiscent of the rules under the Services Directive and clearly aimed at avoiding restrictions derived from professional regulatory regimes. 

On its part, under reg.19(2) PCR2015, contracting authorities can request economic operators to indicate the names and relevant professional qualifications of the staff to be responsible for the performance of the contract, where those personal elements are important--which Dir 2014/24 restricts to public service and public works contracts as well as public supply contracts covering in addition services or siting and installation operations.

This is related to the use of specific expertise and experience as an award criterion under reg.67(3)(b) PCR2015 (which will be commented in due course) and aims to provide contracting authorities with the possibility to ensure that contracts which performance depends on specific skills can be properly facilitated through the selection of an appropriate contractor. In my view, though, those requirements will have to be scrutinized under the principle of proportionality in reg.18(1) PCR2015 (see here).

Groups of economic operators

The general approach to the participation of groups of economic operators in public procurement is clearly flexible and facilitative. This is clear from the fact that reg.19(3) clearly establishes that groups of economic operators, including temporary associations, may participate in procurement procedures and shall not be required by contracting authorities to have a specific legal form in order to submit a tender or a request to participate. Moreover, under reg.19(6), contracting authorities may only require groups of economic operators to assume a specific legal form once they have been awarded the contract, to the extent that such a change is necessary for the satisfactory performance of the contract.

On its part, reg.19(4) determines that contracting authorities may specify how the assessment of compliance with the selection criteria under reg.58 PCR2015 will be carried out, provided that this is justified by objective reasons and is proportionate. In a similar vein, reg.19(5) establishes that any conditions for the performance of a contract by such groups of economic operators which are different from those imposed on individual participants shall also be justified by objective reasons and shall be proportionate.

Consequently, contracting authorities need to discharge a relevant burden of proof for the need of "special rules" for participation by groups of economic contractors. This is particularly in line with the recent case law of the CJEU, such as Swm Costruzioni 2 and Mannocchi Luigino, C-94/12, EU:C:2013:646, which clearly signaled that restrictions on group participation are to be assessed under a very stringent test (see my comment here).

Don't skip a beat: CJEU intends to strengthen consumer protection of medical devices, but does it? (C-503/13)

In the interesting Judgment in Boston Scientific Medizintechnik, C-503/13, EU:C:2015:148, the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU) has clarified the requirements for the application of the EU rules on liability for damage caused by defective products to the manufacturers of potentially defective medical devices which substitution require surgical intervention. 

In the case at hand, the issue was whether the manufacturer of potentially defective pacemakers and implantable cardioverter defibrillators was liable to cover the cost of surgery and related damages to patients that needed those potentially defective products replaced. 

In a clear and rather short Judgment, the CJEU has ruled that such situations are covered by the special liability regime. This is bound to trigger commercial adjustments in this sector, as well as in the insurance sector and I would not be surprised if the Boston Scientific Medizintechnik is strongly criticised. I can think of some reasons why, which I sketch below.

The key controversial legal issues were whether the mere fact that a specific product is potentially defective suffices to classify it as defective for the purposes of EU law and, if so, whether the surgery needed to replace (potentially) defective medical devices was within the scope of the damages imposed on the producer. The CJEU has answered both questions in the affirmative. Some of its reasoning is worth considering in detail.

Firstly, regarding the way in which potentially defective medical devices should be treated, the CJEU determined that
37 ... a product is defective when it does not provide the safety which a person is entitled to expect, taking all the circumstances into account, including the presentation of the product, the use to which it could reasonably be expected that it would be put and the time when the product was put into circulation. Moreover ... that assessment must be carried out having regard to the reasonable expectations of the public at large.
38 The safety which the public at large is entitled to expect ... must therefore be assessed by taking into account, inter alia, the intended purpose, the objective characteristics and properties of the product in question and the specific requirements of the group of users for whom the product is intended.
39 With regard to medical devices such as the pacemakers and implantable cardioverter defibrillators at issue in the main proceedings, it is clear that, in the light of their function and the particularly vulnerable situation of patients using such devices, the safety requirements for those devices which such patients are entitled to expect are particularly high.
40 Moreover, as observed, in essence, by the Advocate General at point 30 of his Opinion, the potential lack of safety which would give rise to liability on the part of the producer ... stems, for products such as those at issue in the main proceedings, from the abnormal potential for damage which those products might cause to the person concerned.
41 Accordingly, where it is found that such products belonging to the same group or forming part of the same production series have a potential defect, it is possible to classify as defective all the products in that group or series, without there being any need to show that the product in question is defective
(C-503/13, paras 37 to 41, emphasis added).
This is a very significant line of reasoning, as it clearly establishes that the potential for damage is an element to take into consideration when assessing the level of safety that users of specific products can expect. In that regard, the higher the potential for damages (in this case, possibly, death), the lower the threshold for the special liability regime to be applicable. This basically comes to create a further objectification of the test for the imposition of objective liability under the EU rules and, in my view, significantly raises the financial risks faced by producers of medical devices. 

A law and economics detailed assessment would be necessary, but this case seems like a good candidate in the list of cases where the good intentions of the CJEU may create unforeseen and undesirable effects, eg by imposing additional costs on producers of medical devices that they pass-on to consumers, ultimately pricing out those with a lower acquisition power [for general discussion, see A Sanchez Graells,  The Importance of Assessing the Economic Impact of the Case Law of the Court of Justice of the European Union: Some Exploratory Thoughts (April 18, 2013)].

An alternative approach could have been explored by focusing on the level of security that medical professionals could expect, as medical devices are clearly not products directly offered to their end users. More alternatives could have been explored in view of the fact that the claimants in the case are mandatory insurance funds and not the ultimate users of the medical devices, which could also have triggered an analysis of the justification for medical insurance itself and the eventual obligation of medical insurers to absorb some of the risks they are perceived to insure. However, none of these issues are addressed by the CJEU in its Boston Scientific Medizintechnik Judgment.

http://candorville.com/2013/08/16/hypocritical-oath/

Secondly, regarding the classification of the surgery costs and related damages as "damage caused by death or by personal injuries" for the purposes of EU law, the CJEU made a distinction based on the recommendations of the manufacturer as to how best to minimise or reduce the risk derived from the potential defect. In that regard, it is worth stressing that
49 Compensation for damage thus relates to all that is necessary to eliminate harmful consequences and to restore the level of safety which a person is entitled to expect...
50 As a consequence, in the case of medical devices, such as pacemakers and implantable cardioverter defibrillators, which are defective ... compensation for damage must cover, inter alia, the costs relating to the replacement of the defective product.
51 In the present case ...
[the manufacturer/importer] recommended to surgeons that they should consider replacing the pacemakers in question.
52 In that case, the Court finds that the costs relating to the replacement of such pacemakers, including the costs of the surgical operations, constitute damage ... for which the producer is liable...
53 That finding may be different in the case of implantable cardioverter defibrillators, as
[the manufacturer/importer] recommended ... that the magnetic switch of those medical devices should simply be deactivated.
54 In that regard, it is for the national court to determine whether, having regard to the particularly vulnerable situation of patients using an implantable cardioverter defibrillator, the deactivation of the magnetic switch is sufficient for the purpose of overcoming the defect in that product, bearing in mind the abnormal risk of damage to which it subjects the patients concerned, or whether it is necessary to replace that product in order to overcome the defect
(C-503/13, paras 49 to 54, emphasis added).
In my view, this nuanced approach of the CJEU that makes the imposition of liability dependent on the recommendation issued by the manufacturer/importer of the potentially defective medical devices is tricky. On the one hand, it shows some space for technical considerations and allows manufacturers to take responsibility in finding the best ways to correct the defect or substitute the defective product. 
 
On the other hand, however, the CJEU is not very clear on this point and hints at the fact that the "particularly vulnerable situation of patients using an implantable cardioverter defibrillator" may tilt the national court's assessment on whether the manufacturer/importer's recommendation was actually fit for purpose. Once more, the focus seems to be in the wrong place, as the technical criteria of the doctors is not being taken into consideration.

If doctors performed an operation to substitute certain medical devices despite the fact that the manufacturer/importer had recommended a less intrusive approach, the medical criterion should be taken into account and, most likely, prevail. A doctor under the Hippocratic Oath is under a duty not to impose (unnecesary) suffering or damage. In this specific context, a doctor would be liable for performing an unnecessary surgery to replace a potentially defective medical device that could be satisfactorily fixed in an alternative way.
 
Hence, determining that the intervention was not necessary (ie releasing the manufacturer/importer from liability) would almost automatically trigger liability for the doctor. This, again, would create undesirable incentives for physicians, who would abstain from replacement surgery where the manufacturer/importer recommendation was different. In that case, there would be no technical check on the manufacturer/importer's views, and users (rectius, patients) could be at a clear disadvantage.

All in all, then, I think that the CJEU's Boston Scientific Medizintechnik Judgment creates significant distortions in the incentives that all parties involved have when medical devices are potentially defective. In my view, this derives from a lack of thought on the implications derived from the fact that medical devices are not acquired freely or willingly by their users, but under a strong prescriptive supervision by the medical profession. And that, in turn, their activities are further overseen (and influenced) by medical insurers. This is something that I would like to see gain more space in future Judgments or, otherwise, the consumerization of healthcare will end up actually under-protecting patients.

Principles of procurement under Reg.18 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

One of the relevant changes introduced by Directive 2014/24 is that is has for the first time consolidated the "general principles of procurement" that have emerged from the case law of the CJEU into a specific provision, hence raising the relevance of compliance with these general principles where contracting authorities exercise their administrative discretion. 

This approach could seem at first sight easier to fit in a civil law context than a common law approach to public procurement. However, it can hardly be doubted that English Administrative Law is based on general principles that are fundamentally aligned with those derived from EU Administrative Law [for discussion, see P Cane, Administrative Law, 5th edn, Clarendon Law Series (Oxford, OUP, 2011) 9-11]. In my view, this approach should not be seen as a legal transplant and much less create any irritation in the context of the transposition of the EU procurement rules.

Art 18(1) Dir 2014/24 indeed sets out that procurement needs to be conducted in accordance with the principles of equality, non-discrimination, transparency, proportionality and competition [for discussion on the implicit existence of this principle under the previous set of EU rules, see A Sanchez Graells, Competition and the Public Buyer Towards a More Competition-Oriented Procurement: The Principle of Competition Embedded in EC Public Procurement Directives (May 15, 2009)].

On its part, Art 18(2) establishes an obligation for Member States to ensure the legality of procurement, particularly as compliance with applicable obligations in the fields of environmental, social and labour law established by international, EU and national law, as well as collective agreements.

Reg.18 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) follows closely the first set of issues regulated in Art 18(1) Dir 2014/24 and also determines that procurement needs to be conducted in accordance with the principles of equality, non-discrimination, transparency, proportionality and competition [reg.18(1) PCR2015]. Particularly in regards with the principle of competition, it is worth noting that reg.18(2) and (3) adopt the same wording as Art 18(1)II Dir 2014/24, which carries the interpretative difficulties created by the EU rule (see my comments here).

It may seem surprising that reg.18 PCR2015 does not include the content of Art 18(2) Dir 2014/24. However, a possible explanation is that the UK government has interpreted that the obligations it imposes are incumbent upon the State itself, which may make them unfit for incorporation into domestic regulations addressed at contracting authorities, because its wording establishes that "Member States shall take appropriate measures to ensure that in the performance of public contracts economic operators comply with ...". 

An alternative to the omission of this provision would have been to draft it as imposing an obligation on the specific contracting authority to take appropriate measures to ensure that in the performance of public contracts economic operators comply with environmental, social and labour law obligations. However, it should not be surprising that a Member State (and the UK at that) would want to avoid making that obligation so specific.

In any case, though, such an omission does not create any gap in the transposition of the EU rules, particularly in view of the fact that reg.56(2) PCR2015 establishes the same duty/possibility than Art 56(2) Dir 2014/24 for contracting authorities to "decide not to award a contract to the tenderer submitting the most economically advantageous tender where they have established that the tender does not comply with applicable obligations in the fields of environmental, social and labour law established by EU law, national law, collective agreements or by the international environmental, social and labour law provisions listed in Annex X to the Public Contracts Directive as amended from time to time." (which is in itself problematic, as commented in due course).

Procurements involving defence or security aspects which are awarded or organised pursuant to international rules under Reg.17 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg.17 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) transposes Art 17 of Directive 2014/24 almost word by word. Similarly to the relationship between regs.4 and 16 PCR2015 regarding mixed procurement including elements of defence and security, reg. 17 PCR2015 establishes rules especial to those in reg.9 for public contracts and design contests involving defence or security aspects which are awarded or organised pursuant to international rules (for discussion of reg.9 on procurement pursuant to international rules generally, see here and here).

Indeed, it should be reminded that reg.9(4) PCR2015 (and art 9(3) dir 2014/24) introduces an (unnecessary) cross-referral to the rules applicable to defence and security procurement for those cases in which the specific "international" procurement concerns goods, works or services covered by the special rules. Hence, once more, it will be interesting to try to identify to what extent the rules under reg.17 differ from those under reg.9 PCR2015.

In that light, it is worth reminding that reg.9 PCR2015 established three basic rules: 1) it creates space for compliance with international law obligations; 2) it creates a specific criterion that money rules, so that procurement funded by international organisations or international funders is subjected to their procurement processes; and 3) it allows for negotiated solutions to mix-funded projects, where the international organisations/funders only provide part of the funds.

Surprisingly (or maybe not), reg.17 PCR2015 establishes the same three basic rules, so that: 1) the rules of Part 2 do not apply to procurement carried out under an international law framework, ie in compliance with the an international agreement or arrangement (including those for the stationing of troops and concerning the undertakings of a member State or a third country) [reg.17(1) PCR2015]; 2) it replicates a specific criterion that money rules, so that procurement  involving defence or security aspects that is funded by international organisations or international funders is subjected to their procurement processes [reg.17(2) PCR2015]; and 3) it allows for negotiated solutions to mix-funded projects, where the international organisations/funders only provide part of the funds [reg.17(3) PCR2015].

The only difference between regs.9 and 17 PCR2015 (and arts 9 and 17 dir 2014/24) is in the specific international law instruments that give rise to the exception under the first rule (ie recognition of international law obligations). While reg.9(1)(a) refers to "a legal instrument creating international law obligations, such as an international agreement, concluded in conformity with the Treaties,", reg.17(1)(a) and (b) refer to "an international agreement or arrangement, concluded in conformity with the Treaties" and simply to "an international agreement or arrangement", respectively.

The reader will forgive my limited knowledge of international public law (see Pedro's diverging approach and the enlightening comment that our colleague Dr Paolo Vargiu posted below), but those provisions create no difference whatsoever in my view. The definition in Art 2(1)(a) of the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties refers to "Treaties" as "international agreement(s) concluded between States in written form and governed by international law, whether embodied in a single instrument or in two or more related instruments and whatever its particular designation" (emphasis added). If one resorts to the sources of international law as described in Art 38 of the Statute of the International Court of Justice, there is only one definition/description of internal law that derives from explicit agreements between States, and it refers to them as "international conventions, whether general or particular, establishing rules expressly recognized by the contesting states" [art 38(1)(a)]. It is the general consensus, as far as I can grasp it, that "Treaties can be referred to by a number of different names: international conventions, international agreements, covenants, final acts, charters, protocols, pacts, accords, and constitutions for international organizations. Usually these different names have no legal significance in international law." [Treaties and International Agreements introductory guide, Berkeley Law, accessed 10/03/2015].

Consequently, in my view, reg.17 PCR2015 (and art 17 dir 2014/24) is completely redundant of the rules in reg.9 PCR2015 (and art 9 dir 2014/24) and should have been omitted in the interest of simplification. It would have sufficed, if anything was actually necessary, to include a simple definition (or a reference) along the lines of that in Art 2(1)(a) of the Vienna Convention on the Law of the Treaties. In my view, this is probably a symptom of a deeper problem derived from excessive specialization of law drafters and policy-makers, but that is a conversation for some other time.

Mixed procurement involving defence or security aspects under Reg.16 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg. 16 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) is concerned with mixed procurement involving defence or security aspects. As Pedro has pointed out, it raises again issues concerning the divisibility or indivisibility of mixed contracts (see comments to reg.4 PCR2015 here and here), as well as some interpretative difficulties derived from the change in drafting adopted in the transposition--as compared to the technically not much better Art 16 of Directive 2014/24

One of the points to note is that reg.4(3) PCR2015 expressly excluded the application of the rules in that regulation "where part of a given contract is covered by Article 346 of TFEU or the Defence and Security Regulations", in which case reg. 16 PCR2015 applies instead. The justification for that exclusion is that, despite the fact that the criteria on how to determine the subjection of mixed contracts to a specific set of rules are broadly common under both regs.4 and 16 PCR2015 (ie both are based on whether the different elements of a procurement are separable), reg.16 PCR2015 (and art 16 Dir 2014/24) are apparently more permissive in excluding the applicability of the general rules to the entirety of the procurement.

As a reminder, for not defence and security related mixed contracts, reg.4 PCR2015 established two basic or main groups of rules. Firstly, if the several parts of a contract were separable, contracting authorities were allowed to tender each part separately under the specific rules applicable to that part (provided there was no avoidance of the applicable rules due to the separation of the different parts of the contract into different procurements). This was not particularly clear were all parts of the contract are covered by Part 2 PCR2015, but it was submitted that this was the best interpretation of the rules, in view of their EU origin.

Secondly, reg. 4 PCR2015 established different rules when the several parts of a contract were not separable. On the one hand, where a contract had elements covered by different rules under Part 2 of the PCR2015, the contract had to be tendered "in accordance with the provisions applicable to the type of procurement that characterises the main subject-matter of the contract in question", if necessary, calculated "in accordance with which of the estimated values of the respective services, or of the respective services and supplies, is the highest". On the other hand, where some parts were covered by Part 2 PCR2015 and other parts were not covered, "the applicable legal regime shall be determined on the basis of the main subject-matter of that contract".

Consequently, as general principles, reg. 4 PCR2015 established, first, that divisible contracts could be either tendered as a single contract (implicitly) under the rules of Part 2 PCR2015 or as separate discrete contracts, each under its rules. And, second, that indivisible contracts had to be tendered under the rules corresponding to the main subject-matter of that contract. This later part is the one that reg.16 PCR2015 deviates from.

At a first level, reg.16(2) and (3) PCR2015 repeat the general rule that where the different parts of a given public contract are objectively separable, contracting authorities may choose to award separate contracts for the separate parts or to award a single contract, always provided that decision is not taken for the purpose of excluding contracts from the application of the relevant rules. In that case, each contract is to be procured under the rules applicable to that specific part [reg.16(4) PCR2015]. So far, the rule is fundamentally the same as under reg.4 PCR2015.

At a second level, reg.16(5) to (7) PCR2015 impose less stringent rules for contracts not necessarily indivisible, but where "the award of a single contract is justified by objective reasons", in which case they can be excluded from compliance with Part 2 PCR2015 if one of their parts is covered by either Art 346 TFEU or the special defence and security procurement rules, regardless of "the applicable legal regime ... on the basis of the main subject-matter of that contract".

At a third level, reg.16(8) PCR2015 also establishes that "where the different parts of a given contract are objectively not separable, the contract may be awarded without applying this Part where it includes elements to which Article 346 of TFEU applies; otherwise it may be awarded in accordance with the Defence and Security Regulations." 

All in all, then, and regardless of the specific anti-circumvention rule in reg.16(3) PCR2015 ("The decision to award a single contract shall not ... be taken for the purpose of excluding contracts from the application of either this Part or the Defence and Security Regulations"), it does set up a system where there is no vis attractiva for Part 2 PCR2015 rules, and contracting authorities are able to exclude its application not only when the contract is indivisible and the main subject-matter of that contract is not covered by those rules (which would be the result under reg.4 PCR2015), but a) when that contract is indivisible and includes elements covered by Art 346 TFEU or defence and procurement rules, or b) is divisible but there is an objective reason for the award of a single contract under rules other than those of Part 2 PCR2015.

Consequently, it is a regime clearly geared towards facilitating the exclusion of compliance with general procurement rules in the case of mixed contracts. Nonetheless, in my view, the key to its interpretation and practice will hinge on the constraints that the CJEU (or domestic courts?) consider that reg.16(3) PCR2015 effectively creates. Once more, I would consider reg.18 PCR2015 (Art 18(1) Dir 2014/24) essential in that determination, as the principles of proportionality and competition should become regulatory devices of the exercise of this sort of discretion.

Defence and Security Procurement under Reg.15 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg.15 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) establishes coverage rules for defence and security procurement that aim to coordinate the general rules with those of the Defence and Security Public Contracts Regulations 2011 (derived from the transposition of Directive 2009/81). 

The content of reg.15 is identical to that of Art 15 of Directive 2014/24 with some minor drafting and structural changes, which deserve no further comment (cf Pedro's more elaborate view here). For an in-depth analysis of the rules applicable to defence and  security procurement, as well as the coordination issues that such a special regime creates, see M Trybus, Buying Defence and Security in Europe. The EU Defence and Security Procurement Directive in Context (Cambridge, CUP, 2014).

Research and Development Services under Reg.14 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg. 14 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) subjects certain R&D services to its Part 2 public procurement rules if the benefits of the R&D services accrue exclusively to the contracting authority for its use in the conduct of its own affairs, and the service provided is wholly remunerated by the contracting authority. This is an almost literal transcription of Art 14 of Directive 2014/24 and deserves no comment (however, see Pedro's remarks, which are interesting).

Is Inter-Environnement Wallonie alive? It is, but the CJEU does not maximise use of Directive's anticipatory effects (C-104/04)

In Federconsorzi and Liquidazione giudiziale dei beni ceduti ai creditori della Federconsorzi (Federconsorzi), C-104/14, EU:C:2015:125, the Court of Justice of the EU (CJEU) has addressed a rather obscure issue of succession of exemptions to comply with EU Directives that I find interesting. In my view, the underlying issue is one of good faith and estoppel related to the case law on anticipatory effect of Directives [such as Inter-Environnement Wallonie and Mangold; see M Klamert, The Principle of Loyalty in EU Law, Oxford Studies in European Law (Oxford, OUP, 2014) 76-77], although the CJEU has reached a different solution in Federconsorzi.


The preliminary reference sent by the Corte suprema di cassazione (Italy) concerned certain difficulties in the transition from the implementation of Directive 2000/35 to that of Directive 2011/7, both of them on combating late payment in commercial transactions, regarding Italian legislation modifying the interest on a debt predating those directives to the detriment of a State creditor.

Due to Italian post-WWII mechanisms to ensure supply of certain agricultural products that were in place until 1967, a large number of agricultural cooperatives held a significant volume of credit against the State (about €512 mn) due to the management of that centralised supply of cereals and other agri-food products. That debt was assigned to Federconsorzi (now in liquidation) in 1999 as part of a broader reform of the legislation applicable to agricultural cooperatives. The applicable 1999 legislation determined that the credits held by Federconsorzi against the State "up to 31 December 1997, shall be satisfied by the allocation [...] of government securities by the Minister for the Treasury, the Budget and Economic Planning". 

This rule was complemented in 2003 by a provision whereby the “interest referred [applicable to those credits] is calculated up to 31 December 1995 on the basis of the official discount rate, plus 4.4 points, with annual capitalisation, and for the years 1996 and 1997, only at the statutory interest rate.” In 2012 there was a further reform of these rules, whereby all outstanding credits against Federconsorzi (not only those up to 31.12.97) "shall bear interest calculated up to 31 December 1995 on the basis of the official discount rate, plus 4.4 points, with annual capitalisation, and for the subsequent period only at the statutory interest rate."

In simple terms, Federconsorzi's claim is that both the 2003 and the 2012 reforms impose a detriment on the State creditors by setting too low interest rates on debts accrued after 1995, which would run contrary to (both the 2000 and 2011) EU rules on combating late payment in commercial transactions. The difficulty from a technical perspective is that Italy opted to limit the temporal effects of both Dir 2000/35 and Dir 2011/7 in their respective transpositions, so that the rules derived from Dir 2000/35 did not apply to contracts concluded before 8 August 2002, and those transposing Dir 2011/7 only apply to transactions concluded on or after 1 January 2013.

The most interesting point is thus to determine whether the legally-mandated changes (ie reduction or cap) of the interest rates applicable to credits derived from pre-existing contracts with Federsconsorzi, but which were enacted in the period of effectiveness of the rules transposing Dir 2000/35 (both of them happened between 8 Aug 2002 and 1 Jan 2013) and one of them during the period for transposition of Dir 2011/7, are contrary to EU law--implicitly, at least in the second case, on the basis of the latter's anticipatory effect.

The CJEU has found that the relevant provision of EU law, including the third paragraph of Art 288 TFEU, "must be interpreted as not precluding a Member State which has made use of the option under Article 6(3)(b) of Directive 2000/35 [ie has limited its effects to after 8 August 2002] from adopting, during the period prescribed for transposition of Directive 2011/7, legislative provisions, such as those at issue in the main proceedings, which are capable of modifying, to the detriment of a creditor of the State, the interest on a debt arising out of the performance of a contract concluded before 8 August 2002.

The reasoning followed by the CJEU to reach this conclusion deserves some closer look. According to the CJEU,
31 ... the option for a Member State, when transposing Directive 2000/35, of excluding contracts concluded before 8 August 2002, as the Italian Republic did [...] is expressly provided for in Article 6(3)(b) of that directive and, when exercised, that option has the effect of rendering all the provisions of that directive inapplicable ratione temporis to those contracts.

32 Furthermore, modifications to the disadvantage of a creditor of the State, made by a legislative act adopted during the period prescribed for transposition of Directive 2011/7, of the interest on a debt arising from the performance of a contract concluded before 16 March 2013 may not in any event be regarded as being capable of seriously compromising the attainment of the objective pursued by that directive (see judgment in Inter-Environnement Wallonie, C‑129/96, EU:C:1997:628, paragraph 45), as Article 12(4) of that directive gives Member States the option of excluding contracts concluded before that date, and the Member State concerned could therefore consider exercising that option.

33 Consequently, it does not follow from the obligation to transpose Directive 2011/7, nor can it be inferred from Article 12(3) of that directive, allowing Member States to retain or adopt provisions more favourable to the creditor than the provisions necessary to comply with that directive, or from Article 7 of that directive, on abusive agreements, terms or practices, that a Member State which has made use of the option under Article 6(3)(b) of Directive 2000/35 may not modify, to the detriment of a creditor of the State, during the period prescribed for transposition of Directive 2011/7, the interest on a debt arising out of the performance of a contract concluded before 8 August 2002, without prejudice, however, to the possibility of there being remedies under domestic law against such a modification
(C-104/14, paras 31-33, emphasis added).
In my view, the reasoning of the CJEU at para 32 of Federconsorzi can be challenged regarding amendments of pre-existing credits that take place during the period of (unexcludable) validity of the Directives. An alternative reading would be that Member States are allowed to keep pre-existing credits as they were prior to 8 August 2002, but they cannot reduce commercial creditor protection because that goes against the very explicit goals of the Directives on combating late payment in commercial transactions

That could easily be squared with the Inter-Environnement test of compromising the objective pursued by the Directives, given that it originally was to "prohibit abuse of freedom of contract to the disadvantage of the creditor. Where an agreement mainly serves the purpose of procuring the debtor additional liquidity at the expense of the creditor ... these may be considered to be factors constituting such an abuse" (rec 19 Dir 2000/35), and did not change later (if not to stress the objective to avoid abuses) with its 2011 rewording: "[t]his Directive should prohibit abuse of freedom of contract to the disadvantage of the creditor. As a result, where a term in a contract or a practice relating to ... the rate of interest for late payment ... is not justified on the grounds of the terms granted to the debtor, or it mainly serves the purpose of procuring the debtor additional liquidity at the expense of the creditor, it may be regarded as constituting such an abuse" (rec 28 Dir 2011/7, emphasis added).


Consequently, I think that once again the CJEU has taken an easy way out in order to provide legal certainty to Member States at the expense of substantive compliance with EU law.

However, the Federconsorzi Judgment at least clarifies two points regarding Directive's anticipatory effect: 1) that it is alive and kicking, in terms of it being a general principle of EU law that, during the period of transposition of a Directive, Member States must refrain from any legislative measure that may "be regarded as being capable of seriously compromising the attainment of the objective pursued by that directive"; and 2) that the easiest option for Member States to avoid that anticipatory effect is to include cut-off deadlines in the Directives themselves.

Contracts subsidised by contracting authorities under Reg.13 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg.13 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) establishes coverage rules for contracts subsidised by contracting authorities, which are identical to those of Art 13 of Directive 2014/24

The rules are straightforward (however, see Pedro's comments) and intend to catch works contracts and services contracts connected to those works when a contracting authority subsidises them by more than 50%, provided: i) their value is above the relevant thresholds (again, including a direct reference to the values in Dir 2014/24, which creates the same issues discussed in relation to reg.5 PCR2015 here and here), and ii) the works involve civil engineering activities as listed in Schedule 2 PCR2015, or building work for hospitals, facilities intended for sports, recreation and leisure, school and university buildings and buildings used for administrative purposes.

The rule that deserves some comment refers to the responsibility of the financing contracting authorities, which "shall ensure compliance" with Part 2 of the PCR2015 (and Dir 2014/24) "where they do not themselves award the subsidised contract or where they award that contract for and on behalf of other entities". 

This provision has been strengthened from its previous wording in Art 8 Dir 2004/18 ("Member States shall take the necessary measures to ensure that the contracting authorities awarding such subsidies ensure", which set a sort of two-tier compliance responsibility that made it rather diffuse, under a sort of "best effort" approach) and now seems to place a much more direct and objective responsibility on funding contracting authorities to ensure compliance with the public procurement rules. 

The issue of liability for lack of compliance with procurement rules in one that is bound to trigger litigation and interpretative difficulties, particularly as cooperative procurement is involved (see comments to regs.37 ff PCR2015 in due course). Hence, it is important to stress that funders of works covered by reg.13 PCR2015 (if they themselves are contracting authorities) retain liability for infringement of the procurement rules, which may well incentivise them to tender the contract directly.

(c) NotFromUtrecht University of Leicester, View of Campus Towers.

Public contracts between entities within the public sector under Reg.12 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

The in-house revolution created by Art 12 of Directive 2014/24 has been transposed by a (not so) simple 'copy-out' in reg. 12 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) on public contracts between entities within the public sector. These provisions consolidate both the public-public cooperation exception (Hamburg) and the in-house providing exception (Teckal) to the EU public procurement rules, but also include significant deviations from the previous case law of the CJEU aimed at creating very ample flexibility for Member States to resort to non-market (?) alternatives to procurement (for critical remarks, see here, here & here; Pedro's comments are here). 

More detailed comments on the novelties at the EU level exceed this blog post and will soon be available in the second edition of my book. In terms of the UK transposition strictly considered, it is worth stressing that reg.12 PCR2015 deviates in two significant ways from art 12 Dir 2014/24, apart from the standard re-ordering and re-numbering of its content.

Firstly, reg.12(1) PCR2015 establishes the conditions under which a contract awarded by a public authority to a controlled (in-house) entity exclude the procurement from compliance with its Part 2 rules. This provision only mentions contracts "awarded by a contracting authority to a legal person" and suppresses the further specification in art 12(1) Dir 2014/24 that such legal person can be "governed by private or public law". In my view, the suppression does not alter the content of the provision and this deserves no further analysis. 

Secondly, reg.12(2) in fine PCR2015 deviates from art 12(2) Dir 2014/24 in a way that could be more relevant. Art 12(2) Dir 2014/24 establishes a new "public-house" extension of the in-house doctrine that covers "inverted" and "horizontal" in-house situations whereby a controlled legal entity awards contracts to its controlling contracting authority, or to another legal person controlled by the same contracting authority. These situations are subject to an alternative condition: either i) that there is no direct private capital participation in the legal person being awarded the public contract; or, as an exception, ii) that the only private capital participation is limited to non-controlling and non-blocking forms of participation required by national legislative provisions, in conformity with the Treaties, and that private capital does not exert a decisive influence.

The difference comes in the wording of this final condition. Whereas art 12(2) Dir 2014/24 requires that "private capital participation ... [does] not exert a decisive influence on the controlled legal person" (emphasis added), reg.12(2) in fine PCR2015 indicates that the requirement is instead for "private capital participation ... [not to] exert a decisive influence on the legal person being awarded the contract", that is, the controlling contracting authority, or another legal person controlled by the same contracting authority. 

The divergence in wording creates some doubts, as it seems to set a control-test applicable to different legal entities depending on whether the "controlled legal person" in the final reference of art 12(2) Dir 2014/24 is understood to be either i) the awarding downstream contracting authority (which would be justified because the provision starts in that way), or ii) the contracting authority to which the contract is awarded and which is the one which private capital participation is being assessed (which is the reading that makes sense from a functional perspective).

In my view, the fact that reg.12(2) in fine clearly opts for this second, functional reading does not result in any significant deviation in the legal test applicable to the new 'public-house' exception where there is legally-mandated private capital participation. The wording of art 12(2) Dir 2014/24 is clearly defective and the wording under reg.12(2) in fine clarifies that both alternative conditions apply to the contracting authority being awarded the contract. Hence, despite the different wording, the transposition seems to remain clearly within the (expanded) limits of the public-public  and in-house exceptions as recast in Dir 2014/24.

Service contracts awarded on the basis of an exclusive right under Reg.11 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg.11 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) creates the first carve-out for (pseudo) public-public cooperation (more to follow under reg.12 PCR2015) and excludes from the rules of Part 2 PCR2015 'public service contracts awarded by a contracting authority to another contracting authority on the basis of an exclusive right which the latter enjoys pursuant to a law, regulation or published administrative provision which is compatible with TFEU.' This is an instance of quasi self-supply, which has been regulated in Art 18 of Directive 2004/18 and is now maintained in Art 11 of Directive 2014/24. The reference to compatibility with the TFEU is primarily to Art 106 and public undertakings (however, see Pedro's expanded view on this).

The rule in Art 11 Dir 2014/24 is fundamentally the same, but reg.11 PCR2015 deviates from the EU provision in that the latter also excludes public services contracts awarded to 'an association of contracting authorities' and, consequently, reg. 11 PCR2015 seems to reduce the flexibility of public-public cooperation rules after their transposition. However, the PCR2015 Explanatory Memorandum offers no justification for such a restriction of the scope of application of this exclusion.

The purpose of the exclusion in reg.11 PCR2015 may seem superficial because both Art 32(2)(b)(iii) Dir 2014/24 and reg.32(2)(b)(iii) PCR2015 allow for the use of a negotiated procedure without prior publication (which is functionally equivalent to an exclusion from compliance with the rules, except for some very limited transparency obligations) where the works, supplies or services can be supplied only by a particular economic operator protected by an exclusive right, including intellectual property rights. However, the specific exclusion in reg.11 PCR2015 may not be considered (completely) superficial or unnecessary if two details are taken into consideration.

Firstly, a literal interpretation (or a natural reading) of reg/art 32(2)(b)(iii) could seem to exclude 'contracting authorities (or associations of contracting authorities' from their scope of application if they were not considered 'economic operators'. However, once this is checked against the definitions in art 2(1)(10) Dir 2014/24 / reg.2(1) PCR2015, it is clear that 'contracting authorities (or associations of contracting authorities' would be covered, as economic operators are defined as 'any natural or legal person or public entity or group of such persons and/or entities, including any temporary association of undertakings, which offers the execution of works and/or a work, the supply of products or the provision of services on the market'. Hence, from this perspective, the specific exclusion in reg.11 PCR2015 seems unnecessary.

Secondly, however, it is worth stressing that the special rule under art/reg 32(2)(b)(iii) 'shall only apply when no reasonable alternative or substitute exists and the absence of competition is not the result of an artificial narrowing down of the parameters of the procurement'. Hence, the specific (quasi) public-public cooperation exception in reg/art 11 seems to be oriented at suppressing the requirement for an assessment of availability of alternative or substitute works, products or services that could be procured. Under this light, this exception seems to now acquire a specific purpose.

In my view, however, if the goal of art/reg 11 is to deactivate the additional requirements of absence of alternative/substitute supplies or artificial narrowing down of the procurement, then these rules are bound to fail and become ineffective. Indeed, it should be stressed here that art/reg 18 include the principle of competition amongst the general principles of procurement and, as a general requirement, impose an obligation for contracting authorities to design the procurement in a way that does not artificially narrow competition. Consequently, a systematic interpretation of art/reg 11 does not allow for an interpretation that is functionally any different than art/reg 32(2)(b)(iii). Thus, ultimately, reg/art 11 is an unnecessary rule and could have been avoided in view of the (proper) public-public and in-house provision rules in Dir 2014/24 and the PCR2015 (commented next).

Specific exclusions for service contracts under Reg.10 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Following the list of specific derogations in Art 10 of Directive 2014/24, reg. 10 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) lists a significant number of services contracts that are excluded from the procurement rules of its Part 2. 

Under the specific exclusions for service contracts, a relatively large number of categories are excluded concerning rental of land, existing buildings or other immovable property, audiovisual and radio programmes, arbitration and conciliation services, legal services, financial services, loans, employment contracts, civil defence, rail and metro transportation services, as well as political campaigns. These exclusions are exactly the same at domestic and EU level and some of them have been included as a result of the suppression of Part B services in the 2014 rules. 

In my view, some of the justifications are easier to support than others. All those concerned with legal services seem quite problematic, though, as there seems to be no clear advantage for the public sector in having unfettered discretion to choose its legal counsel. Similar considerations make the exclusion of financial services dubious. 

Other professional services are covered by the rules in Dir 2014/24 and the PCR2015, which raises the question of which difficulty would there be to choose appropriate providers of legal and financial services under the applicable rules (eg, through a competitive procurement with negotiation with particular requirements in terms of experience and accreditation of the specific members of staff to provide the services, in the case of legal services; or through reverse electronic auctions within a dynamic purchasing system for the provision of financial services, which seems rather close to the liquidity auctions that central banks have been conducting for decades anyway).

In my view (and Pedro's to a large  extent), then, the list of exclusions is excessive and should be pruned. Obviously, one cannot expect the UK to do so unilaterally, particularly in view of the relevance of its legal and financial sectors. However, I would put such a reduction of the list of exclusions in my wishlist for the next round of reform of the EU rules.


Procurement pursuant to international rules under Reg.9 Public Contracts Regulations 2015

Reg.9 of the Public Contracts Regulations 2015 (PCR2015) establishes an exemption for public contracts awarded, and design contests organised, pursuant to international rules and, once more, it follows very closely (but improves) the drafting of Art 9 of Directive 2014/24 (see Pedro's remarks). 

Reg.9 PCR2015 (and art 9 Dir 2014/24) basically creates three specific rules. Firstly, it creates space for compliance with international law obligations, which can become more and more relevant in the immediate future as the EU exercises its external relations powers.

Secondly, it creates a specific criterion that money rules, so that procurement funded by international organisations or international funders is subjected to their procurement processes (this can, however, create difficulties in the integration of rules where the international organisation/funder relies on domestic procedures for all or part of the procurement process, which could create a spiral of cross-referrals). 

Thirdly, it allows for negotiated solutions to mix-funded projects, where the international organisations/funders only provide part of the funds. In this case, it seems logical to require that the applicable rules are at least subjected to requirements of equivalence and effectiveness, so as to avoid infringement of general Treaty rules and the general principles of public procurement (see art 18 dir 2014/24 and reg. 18 PCR2015). 

Finally, reg.9(4) PCR2015 (and art 9(3) dir 2014/24) introduces an (unnecessary) cross-referral to the rules applicable to defence and security procurement for those cases in which the specific "international" procurement concerns goods, works or services covered by the special rules (see reg.17 PCR2015  and art 17 dir 2014/24).

This is a topic where Dr Baudouin Heuninckx has expertly written on repeated occasions [see "Applicable Law to the Procurement of International Organisations in Europe" (2011) 20(4) Public Procurement Law Review 103-22, as well as his Private Contribution to the Commission Green Paper on the modernisation of EU public procurement policy (2011)], so it is worth re-reading his proposals for improvement of the previous rules.

In my view, even if the 2014 rules now implemented by the PCR2015 have created some clarity (cf art 15 Dir 2004/18), there still seems to be room for clarification as to the concepts of "international organisation" or "international financing institution", as well for the introduction of a safeguard clause in case the procedures to be followed under other rules create a gap in scope of coverage or result in otherwise undesirable protectionism or direct award of contracts. However, these are issues that deserve separate analysis and do not affect the PCR2015 exclusively, so they are saved for some other time.

An interesting different take on public procurement decision-making (reference to Crowder, 2015)

I have just read an interesting piece of research that sheds different light on public procurement decision-making processes. That short, accessible and interesting piece, [M Crowder, "Public procurement: the role of cognitive heuristics" (2015) 35(2) Public Money & Management 127-34] explores the cognitive heuristics of public procurement processes. As the abstract makes clear
Public procurement processes have been extensively studied, but previous research has not sought to explain public procurement in terms of cognitive heuristics. This paper examines the award of a large public sector contract and outlines how the decisions were made. Heuristics were used throughout the process. Three heuristics—EBA [elimination by aspects], conjunctive, and WADD [weighted additive]—were used in combination to reduce the number of bidders for the contract from a somewhat unmanageable 63 down to four. This paper allows the underlying stages to be viewed from this perspective and therefore it explores procurement in a way that sheds new light on the processes involved.
The paper is easy to follow if one has some experience in public procurement evaluation or, absent that, some knowledge of the rules on exclusion, qualitative selection and short-listing of tenderers [for a summary of the rules under the new Directive 2014/24, see A Sanchez Graells, “Exclusion, Qualitative Selection and Short-listing”, in F Lichère, R Caranta & S Treumer (eds), Modernising Public Procurement. The New Directive, vol. 6 European Procurement Law Series (Copenhagen, DJØF, 2014) 97-129]. As the conclusions stress, the paper shows
that procurement decisions can be explained in terms of cognitive heuristics. The EBA heuristic makes a decision on the basis of a single aspect; the conjunctive heuristic makes a decision on the basis that a number of requirements are all met; and the WADD heuristic makes a decision by weighing up various factors and offsetting the good against the bad. This was reflected in the procurement under study, where the number of bidders under consideration was reduced in precisely this way.
The paper offers a good perspective to complement our understanding of procurement decision-making and provokes some thoughts on how to better regulate these processes in order to avoid weaknesses derived from cognitive biases. 

This is an area that promises to open roads towards interdisciplinary efforts to incorporate the insights of psychology and other sciences into legal research on public procurement. And this seems to me like an area of high research potential, so it may be worth keeping an eye on it!